At the end of my previous post, I suggested that we might not always want to force people to internalize externalities. This is anathema to most economists and indeed believers in the market as the most efficient allocator of resources. After all, if the market allocates efficiently, and externalities are market failures, then externalities should be corrected. In many cases this will be true, but not, I think in all.
First the argument in favor of internalizing externalities. In the case of positive externalities, if the people generating the benefits are not able to capture the value of those benefits, then they will tend to not produce those goods. Even if these are not public goods, wealth creation is good for its own sake as people will tend to enrich others' lives with their innovations as well as use their wealth to employ other people*. In other words, we want people who are capable of creating new things to create those things, ceteris paribus. If people are not compensated for doing so, they will tend not to bother, or so the argument goes. In the case of negative externalities, if people are not forced to internalize those costs they will tend to over-produce those goods. That's bad for society as well.
To see where this can go wrong, let's take an extreme example. Bill Gates has been the world's richest man, although he's currently #2 behind Carlos Slim. What's more, no one believes that Gates has secured his wealth illegitimately. However, the benefits to the economy of Microsoft's products have not all been captured by Gates. As intermediate goods, Microsoft products allow people to produce other products, and to do so more efficiently than they otherwise might. Though I can't find the study now, a few years back someone estimated that Microsoft had generated hundreds of billions of surplus value to the economy, mostly by reducing transaction costs, improving efficiency in a number of business environments, and generating network externalities. These innovations have literally benefitted hundreds of millions, if not billions, of people all over the world.
You can probably see where I'm going with this. The fact that Gates has not been able to internalize all of the benefits from his products has not stopped him from creating and distributing them. On the contrary: in order for Gates to be as wealthy as he is he has to make sure his products are broadly dispersed, which is why he gives some of them away for free. He has been rewarded very well, but no utilitarian calculus that I'm aware of would suggest that we should redistribute away from ordinary people who have benefitted from Microsoft to Gates. He has more than enough. So we should modify the common claim at the beginning: internalizing (positive) externalities only needs to be done when we're operating near the margin where innovators might choose not to innovate without more compensation. And if we think in those terms, it isn't immediately obvious that we're usually operating at that margin. It is well-known, for example, that popular live music events are generally "inefficient" in that they usually sell out quickly, which indicates that there is quite a lot of surplus that is being captured by consumers rather than producers (or other consumers, who might be willing to pay more for a ticket in an auction setting). Economists generally think this is puzzling, but from a utilitarian perspective it's arguably a very good thing.
How about negative externalities? Arguably this is a more difficult case, but if we keep using the same utilitarian logic I've presented it isn't hard to argue that poorer people should be given some license to push negative externalities onto richer people. People have used this sort of argument to suggest that developing countries should not have to adhere to the same climate change restrictions that richer countries should adhere to. The question is where the margin that tips over into inefficiency lies. I admit that these cases will be much more in the eye of the beholder than the case in which Gates' positive externalities are broadly shared, but there isn't any ex ante reason to discard the idea.
*You don't have to be a believer in strong-form trickle down economics to generally accept this point.
IPE @ UNC
IPE@UNC is a group blog maintained by faculty and graduate students in the Department of Political Science at the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill. The opinions expressed on these pages are our own, and have nothing to do with UNC.
Bookshelf
Tags
Academia Adjustment Afghanistan Africa AIG America Argentina Austerity Bailout Banking Bargaining Basel Bernanke Bias Blogging Business cycle; recession; financial crisis Cap and Trade capital controls capital flows central banks; moral hazard Chavez China China Trade Climate Change Contentious Politics Cuba Currencies Currency Crises; financial crisis Current Account Data Debt Debt; China; United States; Decession Politics Decoupling Deflation democracy Democrats; Trade policy development Diplomacy Dollar; China; Currency Manipulation; Exchange Rates dollar; exchange rate policy ECB ECB; Fed; Monetary Policy Economic Growth Economics Egypt election EMU; monetary union Environment EU; Agriculture; Common Agricultural Policy Euro Europe; labor; immigration European Union Exchange Rates Farm Bill; Agriculture FDI Fed; Monetary Policy finance financial crisis financial crisis; subprime Fiscal Policy; monetary policy; elections Fiscal Stimulus Foreign Aid Foreign Policy France Free Trade Agreements G-20 G20 Summit Game Theory Germany global recession globalization Grand Theory Great Britain Greece health care reform Hegemony Human Rights Iceland imbalance IMF immigration Incentives income distribution income inequality; globalization India Inequality inflation institutions Interests international finance International Law International Monetary System International Relations Investment IPE Iran Iraq Ireland ISA Italy Japan labor markets Latin America Libya Macroeconomics Marxism Mexico Microfinance Miscellany monetary policy Monetary policy; Federal Reserve moral hazard Narcissism Networks Nobelist Smackdown North Korea Obama Oil PIGS Pirates Political Economy Political Methodology Political Science Political Survival Political Theory Power Protectionism Protests Public Choice Public opinion Rational Choice regulation Research Review Russia Sanctions Security Dilemma security threats Soccer Social Science Sovereign Debt Spain Sports Statistics stock markets Systems Tariffs TARP Taxes TBTF Technocracy technology terrorism Trade trade policy UNC Unemployment United States US-South Korea Venezuela WTO WTO; Doha
Blog Archive
-
▼
2011
(365)
-
▼
August
(27)
- This Was Inevitable
- US Stock Markets FOTD
- The Fed Is Political, redux
- Links
- Will US Equity Values Decline Because of Demograph...
- So Let Me Get This Straight
- The Fed Is Political
- This Is What Adjustment Looks Like (an ongoing ser...
- New Economics Research
- Realism, Internationalism, and Networks
- Wanna Bet?
- Financialization and Inflation Rates
- Using Social Science in Russia
- Social Science, Democracy, and Being Contrary
- Daily "Everything Is Screwy" Reminder
- Daily "Everything Is Screwy" Reminder
- Old School Realism and the Problem of Society
- On Michael Lewis on Germany
- Why Hasn't Academic IPE Had Anything to Say About ...
- S&P and Exorbitant Privilege
- Catching Up
- Bigger May Be Different
- Dedicated
- Why We (Sometimes) Shouldn't Internalize Externali...
- Negative Externalities and the Tragedy of the Commons
- Regulatory Politics
- Touche
-
▼
August
(27)
Saturday, August 6, 2011
Why We (Sometimes) Shouldn't Internalize Externalities
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
0 comments:
Post a Comment